It’s not a question of enough…It’s a zero-sum game. Somebody wins. Somebody loses.
– Gordon Gecko, Wall Street
This striking declaration from Gordon Gecko, Michael Douglas’ notorious character from Wall Street, defines free enterprise for many people. It portrays the system as dog-eat-dog competition. Winners always create losers.
This view represents the Zero Sum Game Myth, the third myth in our series on the eight most popular myths of wealth, poverty, and free enterprise.
Myth #3: The Zero Sum Game Myth – believing that trade requires a winner and a loser.
One reason people believe this myth is because they misunderstand how economic value is determined. Economic thinkers with views as diverse as Adam Smith and Karl Marx believed economic value was determined by the labor theory of value. This theory stipulates that the cost to produce an object determines its economic value.
According to this theory, if you build a house that costs you $500,000 to build, that house is worth $500,000. But what if no one can or wants to buy the house? Then what is it worth?
Medieval church scholars put forth a very different theory, one derived from human nature: economic value is in the eye of the beholder. The economic value of an object is determined by how much someone is willing to give up to get that object. This is the subjective theory of value.
Alejandro Antonio Chafuen documents the economic insights of these Christian scholars, in his book Faith and Liberty: the Economic Thought of the Late Scholastics. These Christians believed that,
…the price of goods does not depend on their nature but on the extent to which they serve the needs of mankind…the Late Scholastics posited the idea that the value we place on goods depends on the utility we derive from them.
Human beings, created by God with unique needs, preferences, and opinions, will derive different value from different goods. This led medieval Christian scholars to conclude that value is subjective. Chafuen writes,
The Late Scholastics believed that the pleasure that people derive from different goods is subjective and arises from variability of human opinion, so that different people esteem goods differently.
A clarifying point about “subjective” is needed here. To say “economic value is subjective” is not to say “everything is relative.” We’re talking about economic value, not ultimate value. Your ultimate value in the eyes of God is not the same as economic value.
All of us are created in God’s image. Our equal value and dignity as persons doesn’t vary with the wants and needs of consumers in the marketplace.
Win-Lose, or Win-Win?
How you determine economic value affects whether you view free enterprise as a zero-sum game, or a win-win game in which both participants benefit.
Let’s return to the example of the $500,000 house. As the developer of the house, you hire workers to build the house. You then sell it for more than $500,000. According to the labor theory of value, you have taken more than the good is actually worth. You’ve exploited the buyer and your workers by taking this surplus value. You win, they lose.
Yet this situation looks different according to the subjective theory of value. Here, everybody wins. You market and sell the house for more than it cost to produce, but not more than customers will freely pay. The buyer is not forced to pay a cost he doesn’t agree to. You are rewarded for your entrepreneurial effort. Your workers benefit, because you paid them the wages they agreed to when you hired them.
This illustration brings up a couple important points about free enterprise that are often overlooked:
1. Free exchange is a win-win game.
In win-win games, some players may end up better off than others, but everyone ends up better off than they were at the beginning. As the developer, you might make more than your workers. Yet the workers determined they would be better off by freely exchanging their labor for wages, than if they didn’t have the job at all.
A free market doesn’t guarantee that everyone wins in every competition. Rather, it allows many more win-win encounters than any other alternative.
2. The game is win-win because of rules set-up beforehand.
A free market is not a free-for-all in which everybody can do what they want. Any exchange must be free on both sides. Rule of law, contracts, and property rights are needed to ensure exchanges are conducted rightly. As the developer of the house, you’d be held accountable if you broke your contract and failed to pay workers what you promised.
An exchange that is free on both sides, in which no one is forced or tricked into participating, is a win-win game.
This post is adapted from the book Money, Greed, and God.
Leave your comments here.